How can climate policies be accepted politically?

If recent agreements show the worldwide political willingness to deal with climate change, countries’ promises have yet to be turned into practical policy designs. Carbon Taxes are widely praised by economists as the most efficient way to internalize the social impact of carbon emissions, yet their implementation is still slow. What are the barriers to their implementation and how can governments improve their policy designs? Some insights from a paper recently published.

An article by Alexis Bernigaud

If recent agreements show the worldwide political willingness to deal with climate change, countries’ promises have yet to be turned into practical policy designs. Carbon Taxes, for instance, are widely praised by economists as the most efficient way to internalize the social impact of carbon emissions, yet their implementation is still slow: in 2017, only 20 countries had implemented a carbon tax.

What are the barriers to implementation and how can governments improve their policy designs? We selected three insights from Carattini et al’s paper: Green Taxes in a Post-Paris World: Are Millions of Nays Inevitable?

  • Small Steps rather than Big Dreams
    Citizens’ aversion for high carbon tax rates has been demonstrated by numerous examples of rejected projects, one of the most salient being when 92% of the Swiss voters rejected the Green Liberal’s project to introduce an energy tax that would have tripled gas prices to replace the current value-added tax.
    But on top of the direct negative correlation between tax rates and Yes-votes, an incremental approach is also justified by the fact that people’s aversion often decreases once they have experienced the policy and realized that costs – purchasing power, competitiveness – are lower and societal benefits higher than expected. Governments should then try to gradually introduce carbon taxes, or even use trial periods to earn citizens’ approval.
  • Building Trust
    One of the main arguments against carbon taxes is that governments use them as a backdoor way of raising government revenue. Earmarking tax revenues to finance specific environmental projects is a way to build trust: the literature shows that voters would often rather see the tax money being used to fight climate change than being compensated by tax cuts. Nonetheless, one of the main findings of Carattini’s paper is that, if citizens were given enough evidence to be convinced by the efficiency of carbon taxes to mitigate climate change, they would not need to see the revenues earmarked towards climate change mitigation projects.
  • Making social benefits salient
    Other than earmarking this money for environmental purposes, governments can also redistribute it to taxpayers. In doing so, governments should keep in mind that “Revenue Neutrality”, a concept that allows government to use the revenue raised from a new tax to reduce another tax, keeping the revenue raised constant, is not well understood by the general population: this is one of the reasons why the Swiss rejected the carbon tax project that was supposed to replace the Value Added Tax. Instead of cutting taxes, voters prefer direct per-capita transfers or social cushioning for low-income households, because they perceive the benefits more easily than when a tax decreases. To make these benefits even more salient, the tax may be marketed as a “carbon fee and dividend”: each household could receive a yearly check, a dividend comparable to the very popular Alaska Permanent Fund.

See Carattini et al’s paper: Green Taxes in a Post-Paris World: Are Millions of Nays Inevitable?
See the policy report: How to make carbon taxes more acceptable.

Share

Article

The Climate Change Trap

An escape valve for local tensions. An occasion to adapt to the changing climate. In a future with higher temperatures and rarer natural resources, migration arises as an opportunity for many people to find more hospitable places to live in. An opportunity not for everyone, as migrating is expensive, and especially the most vulnerable and poor might find themselves unable to move, blocked into a trap that climate change can, in turn, worsen by keeping worsening inequalities and poverty.

Article

Entering a Colorful World: the Decade of Action for Sustainable Development

Extreme poverty is decreasing, but inequalities are rising; access to electricity and safe drinking water is improving, but losses in biodiversity are increasing. The Sustainable Development Goals are measuring both progress and delays. Officially launched at the SDGs Summit 2019, the new report “The Future is Now: Science for Achieving Sustainable Development” highlights six “entry points” for accelerating the progress towards the achievement of the 2030 Agenda for Sustainable Development.

Interview

Navigating coastal dynamics and building resilience

Around 40% of the global population resides on coasts, with many relying on coastal resources for sustenance. Climate change exacerbates coastal hazards, compelling decision-makers and asset owners to address coastal resilience. Delphine Lobelle, Climate & Nature advisor at Fugro, highlights the importance of understanding coastal dynamics to empower stakeholders and promote proactive measures for coastal resilience.